Histoire d'Essaouira au 19e siècle

Tafart

Active Member
Staff member
La fondation de la ville et du port au 18e. siècle devait faciliter le commerce internationale et en meme temps le controle du sudouest du pays, le Souss ne particulier, contre la dissidence. Source: Merchants Of Essaouira Urban Society and Imperialism in Southwestern Morocco, 1844–1886.

"Essaouira was the most important seaport in Morocco for a century, but compared with the growing port cities in the colonial area, this outlet to Europe was a backwater. Essaouira remained a small city, situated in a relatively barren region. The expansion of other Middle Eastern seaports, such as Beirut and Alexandria, was dramatic in the same period. Beirut's population grew from 6,000 to 120,000 in the nineteenth century. At the beginning of the nineteenth century, Alexandria had a population of 10,000; already by the mid 1850, the city had grown to about 150,000. Wherever European commercial interests were strong, port cities began to grow into major emporiums of trade. In contrast, Essaouira's small scale growth from 10,000 to 18,000 seems insignificant.

And yet, historians have often seen the development of Essaouira as highly significant in the modern history of Morocco. Abdallah Laroui argues that Sultan Muhammad III, the founder of Essaouira, can be regarded as the 'veritable architect of the "modern" Morocco described in numerous nineteenth- and twentieth-century accounts'. With the creation of Essaouira, in Laroui's view, the bulk of the state revenues were henceforth derived from customs duties on foreign trade. In this way the prosperity and the very existence of the state became dependent on an activity dominated by foreigners.

The stress of almost all studies on Morocco, since the important book of Miège, has been on the social changes engendered by the integration of Morocco into the world capitalist system. Miège postulates that Morocco's interaction with Europe, and in particular foreign trade, led to a structural transformation of society. Capitalism developed on the margins of the traditional economy, and the growing influence of the bourgeoisie - largely Jewish - effected the economic transformation of the country. A capitalist class of farmers and landlords began to develop in both the towns and the countryside. The inland cities declined as the coastal towns grew. As in other parts of the Middle East, traditional crafts were in crisis or disappeared altogether because of the influx of cheap European manufactured goods. These assumptions have guided a number of in-depth studies on how Moroccan society was transformed in specific towns or regions during precolonial times.

These studies are an important departure from the literature of the French colonial period, which depicts Moroccan traditional society before the French protectorate as unchanging. French writings on Moroccan cities tend to focus on the historic monuments of the town and contributions of each successive Sultan to the urban topography, but are little concerned with social change. Even the study of Fez by Roger Tourneau, one of the most important books on Moroccan urban life and the Islamic city generally, largely sees the precolonial city as timeless. Fez in 1900, in many respects, appears the same as in Marinid times. Implicit in this interpretation is that change came about under the aegis of the French protectorate, but as the recent study of André Raymond has shown - in contradistinction to the notion of urban decadence in the Ottoman period - cities of the Middle East and North Africa were developing in significant ways in the centuries preceding the nineteenth century.

In the precolonial period, social change in Moroccan cities was greatly accelerated because of the growing dependency of Morocco on Europe. European commercial expansion can be seen as the first phase in the process of foreign economic predominance, comparable to that which occurred in the countries of the Middle East. Port cities in particular were susceptible to social change, because they were the principal points of contact between Europeans and the local population. Even more important, the ports served as agents of change, bridgeheads in sub-ordinating the country as a whole to dominant western models.

To what degree does Morocco's principal seaport in the nineteenth century fit this general model? How did the local merchants respond to the external forces of change, and how did they themselves act as agents of social and economic transformation? I hope to answer these questions throughout this book by examining local society and its relations with the interior of Morocco. But before I proceed, a few preliminary remarks about Essaouira are called for.

The town was founded by the Sultan to serve as a royal port, an entrepôt where all trade with Europe could be conducted. The aim of the Sultan was both to contain foreign influence and to limit the volume of trade. The town was situated in a relatively isolated location, and foreigners were not allowed to travel to the inland markets. In the town itself, foreigners and Moroccan-Jewish royal merchants were provided with special separate quarters in the casbah. Their premises belonged to the central government. Foreign trade, in theory, was to be closely administered by the makhzan. In many respects this calls to mind Polanyi's 'ports of trade', in which the trading community was relatively isolated from the rest of society, playing the role of political intermediaries between political frontiers. In this paradigm, administered trade, which centres on long distance 'luxury' items, prevails over the economic process of competition. In some respects, the Moroccan Sultan was able to contain foreign penetration and create an economic enclave in the same way, for example, that the Chinese were able to do in their treaty ports. In China, foreigners were confined to a specific quarter in Canton, and not allowed to travel elsewhere (except on special tributary missions to bring gifts to the Emperor) nor trade with other ports. Foreign trade became a state monopoly, and European merchants were compelled to trade with official Chinese intermediaries. Treaty ports grew rapidly in China in the nineteenth century, though their impact on the traditional Chinese economy remained limited

However, it would be misleading to carry this model too far. Essaouira's economic isolation and political neutrality were always relative, and certainly never complete. The urban patterns that evolved came to resemble those of other Muslim cities, and Moroccan cities in particular. Furthermore, the Sultan progressively lost his control of commerce. Essaouira's trade, even from the very beginning of the town's existence, operated according to the practices which were rooted in Moroccan society. Essaouira was therefore both unique, as an administered port of trade, yet similar to other cities. (...)
 
(...)
In light of the size and economic position of the major inland cities of Morocco, the importance of the coastal ports in the socio-economic transformation of Morocco needs to be placed in perspective. The economic importance of the interior, and domestic trade generally, still greatly overshadowed that of the coast. Despite the assertions that the major inland cities of Fez and Marrakesh were in decline, there is little solid evidence to suggest that the rather limited growth of coastal towns was necessarily at the expense, either demographic or economic, of the major inland cities of Morocco. Though there were probably dramatic fluctuations in Marrakesh's population in the nineteenth century, there are no obvious signs of an overall decline in this period. Marrakesh still remained the capital and the most important commercial emporium for southern Morocco. Furthermore, the vast majority of Morocco's population of several million inhabitants resided in the countryside. It can be surmised that the urban population in Morocco ranged between five and ten per cent. The rural population in the hinterland of Essaouira-in the Haha and Shiadma - numbered at least ten times as high as the inhabitants of the town. Morocco, therefore, remained essentially a rural society. Bearing this in mind, the primary concern of the Moroccan Sultan was the control of the countryside. The largest potential source of revenue for the makhzan remained in the rural sector. Recent research in tax registers has revealed that the state derived much more income from the interior than from customs duties at the coast ports in the latter half of the nineteenth century.

The significance of Essaouira, therefore, lay not only in the dependency of the makhzan on customs duties from foreign trade, which were important, but did not constitute the main fiscal resource of the state, but also in its geopolitical position in the control of southwestern Morocco. By linking the fortunes of potentially dissident chiefs of the Sous to the commercial activity of the royal port of Essaouira, the Sultan to keep the more distant parts of the country within the fold. It should be borne in mind that at the beginning of the Alawi dynasty the sultanate was threatened by a rival dynasty of shurafà - men of sacred lineage - from Iligh in the Sous.

This essentially domestic strategy had unforeseeable consequences. By opening up the Sous trade to Europeans, foreign penetration was facilitated, which was to undermine the Sultan's concomitant aim of containing foreign influence and keeping foreign trade at a minimal level. The native merchants of Essaouira themselves served as agents of foreign penetration. The closely controlled system of royal trade was challenged by the fact that the royal merchants (tujjar as-Sulan), like the Chinese compradors, became brokers for the foreign companies doing business in Morocco.

Some of the tujjar as-Sultan became wealthy in their role as middlemen. Yet this wealth itself often implied dependency on Europe. The domestic possibilities for investment remained extremely limited, so the most successful Moroccan merchants invested in foreign banks and companies. This underlines the limitations of their influence in Moroccan society as a whole. Though the tujjar as-Sultan may have tried to emulate western culture, they remained embedded in Moroccan society, and while they were responsible for distributing European imports domestically, they did not restructure the traditional Moroccan economy along western lines. European domination during colonial rule ultimately did transform the Moroccan economy, and integrated the country into a European-based capitalist market economy, but the process of structural change took place much more gradually than historians have admitted. From hindsight one risks interpreting all events and activities relating to foreign trade as steps in the development of capitalism in Morocco. While the ports of trade served as bridgeheads for foreign penetration, in the nineteenth century, they did not subordinate Moroccan culture to a dominant western model. Despite progress of foreign economic penetration, European interests were too limited, and the country remained too resilient for a significant restructuring to occur.

The approach of Miège, which focuses on Morocco's integration into world economic system, needs to be reversed. In this book, I intend to place the trading community of Essaouira in a Moroccan context. Immanuel Wallerstein's important theory on how the 'core' subjugated the 'periphery' provides an interesting conceptual framework for the development of a European world-economy, but it does not take into consideration, as Eric Wolf points out, the reactions of the micro-populations habitually investigated by anthropologists. Morocco was in upheaval because of foreign political and economic penetration, but the continuities of traditional Moroccan society were also propelled by their own dynamics. Through depicting the lives of the people of Essaouira, I hope to give a sense of what Moroccan culture and society was like in the age of European economic expansion."
 
Back
Top